Akram Thesis
Embed Size (px)
Transcript of Akram Thesis
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
1/50
THE EFFECT OF MIGRANT REMITTANCES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH
A Thesissubmitted to the Graduate School of Arts & Sciences
at Georgetown Universityin partial fulfillment of the requirementsfor the degree of Master of Public Policyin the Georgetown Public Policy Institute
By
Theresa A. McCaffrey
Washington, D.C.April 10, 2007
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
2/50
ii
THE EFFECT OF MIGRANT REMITTANCES ON ECONOMIC GROWTH
Theresa A. McCaffrey
Thesis Advisor: Susan Fleck, Ph.D.
ABSTRACT
This study investigates the impact of migrant remittances on economic growth
in the developing countries that receive the remittances. After reviewing the relevant
literature on remittances at both the micro and macro levels, it outlines the research
design for a macro level study on the impact of remittances on growth. The hypothesis
is that remittances can have a positive impact on growth and the model includes
various interaction terms in order to determine the macroeconomic situation under
which this can happen. Ordinary least squares (OLS) and fixed effects regressions are
performed with cross country macroeconomic data from 152 low and middle income
countries from 1990 to 2005. The results suggest that remittances have a positive
impact on growth and that this impact increases at higher levels of remittances relative
to GDP. Additionally, remittances are found to have a more positive impact in
countries with certain characteristics: low domestic credit available, low capital
formation, and low inflation. These results provide further justification for the policy
recommendations currently advocated by many in the development community and
suggest some new policies to increase the developmental impact of remittances that
fall into two broad categories: steering remittances toward the most productive areas
and creating a macroeconomic climate where remittances can have the greatest impact.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
3/50
iii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Chapter 1. Introduction .................................................................................... 1
Chapter 2. Literature Review ........................................................................... 2
Surveys........................................................................................... 2
Data on remittances ........................................................................3
Micro level studies ......................................................................... 5
Macro level studies......................................................................... 7Policy Implications ....................................................................... 13
Chapter 3. Hypothesis and Statistical Model .................................................. 14
Hypothesis.................................................................................... 14
Model........................................................................................... 14
Chapter 4. Research Design ........................................................................... 18
Data Sources................................................................................. 18
Analytic Methodology .................................................................. 18
Chapter 5. Findings........................................................................................ 20
Descriptive Statistics..................................................................... 20Regression Results........................................................................ 24
Chapter 6. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations ................................... 38
Appendix: Correlations between variables ......................................................... 41
References......................................................................................................... 43
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
4/50
1
Chapter 1. Introduction
Remittances, the money sent by migrants working abroad to their home
countries, are increasingly being proposed as a development tool. This is not surprising
considering that remittances constitute a huge international capital flow. Remittances
accounted for an estimated US$232 billion across all countries in 2005, $167 billion of
which was sent to developing countries (World Bank, 2006a). Remittances are second
only to foreign direct investment as a flow of capital to developing countries, and they
are approximately double the amount of official foreign aid given. Although they are
often cited as a good source for development capital, little is known about the actual
impacts of this currency flow. A recent study by the World Bank found remittances to
be effective in reducing poverty (Adams & Page, 2005). However, an IMF study found
them to reduce GDP growth (Chami, Fullenkamp, & Jahjah, 2005). This paper
investigates the impact of remittances on economic growth in developing countries.
Chapter 2 reviews the literature, on both the micro and macro levels, of remittances
and growth. Chapter 3 sets out a hypothesis that remittances can have a positive impact
on growth and proposes a theoretical model for testing this relationship. Chapter 4
contains a research plan and analytic methodology for the research. Chapter 5 presents
the results of the investigation. Chapter 6 concludes and outlines the policy
implications resulting from the study.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
5/50
2
Chapter 2. Literature Review
International migration is increasingly seen as a development opportunity. The
worker who migrates generally improves his or her wages and often increases the
household income through remittances sent to the home country. Little is known about
why the money is sent and its impact on the household even less is known about the
impact on the overall economy of the receiving country. However, international
organizations are beginning to eye this massive capital flow, estimated at around $232
billion in 2005, as a source of funding for development (IMF, 2005 World Bank,
2006a). Though the literature on remittances is growing, what is emerging shows great
variation across countries and studies on the impacts of remittances, both at the micro
and macro levels.
Surveys
For general background on the topic, several authors provide surveys of the
economic implications of migration and remittance sending. Rapoport and Docquier
(2005) review the economics of remittances with a focus on the theoretical aspects.
They include both micro level determinants of remittances and macro level
implications of remittances. Page and Plaza (2005) provide a comprehensive survey of
the issues of remittances and development and consider the policy implications for
both migration and remittances. Brown (2006) looks at recent patterns in remittance
sending and examines the literature, both theoretical and empirical, on the relationship
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
6/50
3
between remittances and development. Ellerman (2003) examines the relationship
between migration and development for both skilled and unskilled workers between a
variety of contexts, north north, south south, and north south. Ratha (2003)
summarizes some key issues dealing with remittances, with an eye toward using them
as a possible development tool. Acosta, Calderon, Fajnzylber, and Lopez (2006)
review the literature associated with Latin American migration and consider micro and
macroeconomic studies of the effect of remittances on poverty.
Data on remittances
Although accurate figures on international migration are scant, remittance
flows are one of the better measured indicators. Even so, available data on remittances
generally capture only money sent through official channels, such as the banking
system or a wire transfer service, and so undercount the amount of money sent.
There are three categories in the balance of payment statistics into which the
money associated with international workers falls (IMF, 1993). Workers
Remittances appears in the current transfers section of the current account and
consists of money transferred by migrants who move to another country for a period of
one year or longer. Compensation of Employees is a component of income in the
current account and represents the wages, salaries, and benefits earned by nonresident
workers who migrate for a period of less than a year. And finally, Migrants
Transfers appears in the capital account section and represents the financial
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
7/50
4
transactions that accompany the change of residence of the worker from one country to
another. Although only the first of these three is officially called remittances, studies of
the economic effects of remittances generally include at least the first two and most
often all three.
There are concerns about the reliability of these data on several counts.
Although the IMF provides a framework, Reinke and Patterson (2005) point out
differences in accounting methods across countries that introduce variation. Some
countries include transfers by migrants under Other Current Transfers instead of the
named category. Other countries count migrants abroad for over a year as residents, so
all of their income appears as compensation of employees, even though much of it is
likely spent in the host country. These problems can be seen in the global imbalances
in credits and debits that exist for workers remittances and compensation of
employees, amounting to about $12 billion in 2003 (Reinke & Patterson, 2005).
Although this difference in definitions is a serious problem, difficulties in obtaining the
necessary data proves to be a still larger one.
A related concern about data accuracy is the extent to which the official flows
capture the total flows of remittances sent by international workers. Acosta et al.
(2006) address this question by comparing balance of payment (BOP) statistics to
household survey data for 10 Latin American countries representing over two thirds of
remittances to Latin America for the period of 2000 2004. They find that remittances
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
8/50
5
in household data are generally less than in BOP data, but by a predictable amount.
Regressing remittance levels from household surveys on those from BOP data,
household survey data can explain about 80 percent of the variance in BOP data, and
BOP remittances statistics tend to be about 70 percent larger than household survey
statistics. They also point out, however, that household surveys may not be taken from
a representative sample of the economy and that these surveys often have error
associated with imperfect recall. However, their analysis does support the acceptability
of using official remittance data to proxy for total remittances. Ratha (2003) cites
anecdotal evidence that the proportion of official remittances is increasing as a result of
international efforts to combat money laundering and the financing of terrorism (p. 43).
Micro level studies
Motivation
There is a wide literature on the distribution and effects of remittances on the
micro level. Economists disagree on whether the sending of remittances is motivated
by altruism or whether they fulfill some economic goal, such as insurance or
investment. Sana (2005), using data from male Mexican migrants in the U.S., finds that
social status and identity are key motivations for remittances. Roberts and Morris
(2004) review the reasons for remitting that are generally given, altruism, insurance,
and investment, and add a fourth reason, access to village based employment
networks.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
9/50
6
Distribution
A second question on the micro level is who the migrants sending these
remittances are and what type of households are receiving these remittances. DeSipio
(2000) looks at how individual migration decisions are made and finds that remittances
decrease as migrants spend more time abroad. Sana and Massey (2005) examine how
migrants remit money using data from migrant communities in four Latin American
countries. They examine the household and family structure in the country of origin
and find that remittances differ across countries in this respect. Acosta et al. (2006)
look at Latin America and find different patterns of remittances by income and
education levels. In some countries, such as Mexico, Guatemala, and El Salvador,
migrants come from and send remittances back to households in the lower levels of the
income distribution. In others, such as Haiti, Peru, and Nicaragua, migrants are
positively selected and come from richer households. There are likewise different
patterns seen in educational attainment levels of migrant and non migrant households
across the sample of countries.
How remittances are used
A key question for determining the economic impacts of remittances is how the
money is used, i.e., whether it is spent or invested. Basok (2003) examines the
investment decisions made by workers in the Canadian Mexican Seasonal Workers
Programme and finds that migrants from the least endowed communities (with respect
to land, infrastructure, and market access) are most likely to invest their earnings in
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
10/50
7
agricultural land. Likewise, from surveys on a household level in Guatemala, Adams
(2005) finds that increased remittances are associated with lower consumption and
higher investment. Orozco (2004) describes the emergence of Hometown Associations
in Mexico, which provide a formal mechanism for migrants to invest in their
communities. In this way, remittances could be an option for financing local
development projects on the grassroots level. Lowell and de la Garza (2004) discuss
this potential throughout Latin America.
Macro level studies
Macroeconomic determinants of remittances
On the macro level, many authors point out that the amount of remittances sent
is influenced by various macroeconomic factors. El Sakka and McNabb (1999)
examine the effect that macroeconomic factors have on remittance sending decisions
using the case of Egypt. The authors find that both exchange rate and interest rate
differentials are significant determinants of official remittance flows. They also find a
high income elasticity for imports paid for by remittances. Studies by Gammeltoft
(2002) and Buch and Kuckulenz (2004) compare remittances to other capital flows and
find them to be more stable than private and official capital flows. Chami et al. (2005)
point out that remittances operate in a counter cyclical manner, with migrants remitting
more money when their relatives at home are worse off. They point out the moral
hazard inherent in this situation since the sender is not able to verify whether or not
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
11/50
8
those at home are working diligently. Bugamelli and Patern (2005) also mention the
countercyclical nature of remittances and point out that this may reduce the probability
of current account reversals. However, Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) dispute this
conventional wisdom and show that the counter or pro cyclical nature of remittances
varies by country and highlight the role of financial development (discussed below).
Lueth and Ruiz Arranz (2006) develop a bilateral database of remittance flows based
on eleven countries in Europe and Asia that track this data. They develop a gravity
model for determinants of remittances and find that more than 50 percent of the
variation in remittances can be explained by the GDP differences, distance, and
common language between the two countries. They find trade linkages and colonial
ties to be significant as well.
Poverty and inequality
Although remittances transfer money to households in poor countries, the
question of whether or not they reduce poverty on a macro level depends on other
factors. Adams and Page (2005) examine the relationship among migration,
remittances, and poverty, using census data from the U.S. and OECD countries in
Europe to find migration numbers by country of origin. They acknowledge various
incomplete aspects of their data, including their lack of migration statistics from the
Arab Gulf countries and their reliance on official remittance data. To account for the
endogenous nature of migration and remittances, they use an instrumental variables
approach with three instruments: distance from remittance sending area (U.S., OECD
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
12/50
9
Europe, or Arab Gulf) to receiving country, education (percent of population over age
25 that has completed secondary school), and government stability. In their analysis,
the authors control for income level, since the migrant abroad no longer contributes to
the family income. They find that both migration and remittances have a statistically
significant negative impact on poverty, and a larger impact when using the
instrumental variables approach to control for endogeneity. Using OLS regression,
they find that, for a 10 percent increase in share of international migrants, poverty
headcount (measured at $1/person/day) will decrease by 2.1 percent on average. After
instrumenting for endogeneity, this decrease in poverty rises to 3.5 percent. Gupta,
Pattillo, and Wagh (2007) similarly find that remittances reduce poverty in their cross
country analysis, with an even larger impact seen in Sub Saharan Africa,. They deal
with the endogeneity of remittances through a three stage least squares system of
regressions.
However, other studies provide contrasting results. Bracking (2003) looks at
remittances in Zimbabwe and finds that, although they benefit households who receive
them, they have an adverse effect on households without migrants, due to both asset
price inflation and the inflationary effects of parallel currency markets. Acosta et al.
(2006) examine the literature of micro level studies of the impact of remittances on
inequality and poverty throughout Latin America and find that a one percentage point
increase in remittances as a share of GDP lowers the poverty headcount by about 0.4
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
13/50
10
percent, which they judge to be an insubstantial impact. They also find no substantial
impact of remittances on inequality in Latin America. In addition to their effect on
poverty, remittances can also improve other important indicators, especially health and
education indicators, for receiving households (Kanaiaupuni & Donato 1999).
Growth
Chami et al. (2005) published a seminal account of remittances and growth, in
which they develop a model of remittances, based on the unit of the family and
motivated by altruism. Their model shows that remittances vary counter cyclically and
contain an element of moral hazard. They regress growth against initial income,
investment, and remittances and find that remittances are negatively correlated with
growth. Although they acknowledge the endogeneity of remittances in their
countercyclical model, they do not correct for it. Nonetheless, most of the subsequent
literature on remittances and growth uses their article as a starting point, whether or not
it supports their conclusions.
Another study (IMF, 2005) uses an instrumental variables approach to examine
the relationship of remittances to growth and to control for endogeneity. The
instruments employed are the distance between the remittance receiving country and
the remittance sending country with the largest number of migrants and whether these
two countries share a common language. It finds no significant link between growth
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
14/50
11
and remittances in the general sample of countries nor in a subset of remittance
dependent countries in which remittances account for more than one percent of GDP.
However, there are studies with a more positive view of the contribution of
remittances on growth. Ziesemer (2006) examines the role of remittances, through
contributions to physical and human capital in economic growth, by using two
different open economy models. He uses a general method of moments with
heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation with pooled data for four groupings of countries
receiving remittances in 2003. He finds that the countries that benefit the most from
remittances are those with per capita income below $1,200. For these countries,
remittances contribute about 2 percent to steady state level of GDP per capita versus
having no remittances. The effect of remittances on growth in richer countries is found
to be much smaller. Glytsos (2005) uses a Keynesian econometric model to estimate
short and long run multipliers of remittances, and then determines the impact of
remittances on growth in five Mediterranean countries. He maintains that remittances
can have a positive impact on growth, not only if they are directed towards investment,
but also through the increased consumption and imports. He considers only the demand
impact of remittances, but finds great fluctuations across time and countries for the
effect of remittances on growth.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
15/50
12
Growth and financial development
Another thread of the literature on remittances and growth looks at their impact
particularly in countries with low levels of financial development, on the theory that
remittances may provide capital for investment in countries without widespread access
to credit. Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) examine the impact of remittances and
financial development on growth and find that, although in general remittances do not
have a significant effect on growth, the impact is positive and significant in countries
with low financial development (measured in four ways loans, deposits, credit, or M2
as a percentage of GDP). Mundaca (2005) uses data from Central America, Mexico,
and the Dominican Republic to look at the impact of growth volatility, remittances, and
financial development on growth, on the theory that economic volatility will influence
how remittances are spent or invested. She finds that remittances have a positive and
significant effect on growth in all specifications of her model, although none of the
specifications include interaction terms between remittances and volatility or
remittances and financial development, both of which would seem to be of primary
importance. Looking at the issue from a different angle, Aggarwal, Demirguc Kunt,
and Martinez Peria (2006) and Gupta et al. (2007) find a positive impact of remittances
on financial development. So financial development could prove to be a pathway by
which remittances bring about economic growth.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
16/50
13
Policy Implications
The development literature and discourse is now filled with recommendations
on what should be done to enhance the development impact of remittances (Kapur,
2004 Sriskandarajah, 2005 Terry & Wilson, 2005 Brown, 2006). Suggestions cover a
huge range of policy topics and include relaxing foreign exchange controls, lowering
the costs of sending remittances, making international labor markets more flexible,
giving international institutions a role in a remittance sending framework, combating
brain drain, promoting circular migration, and encouraging collective remittances.
Orozco and Fedewa (2006) mention a range of the policy options that can be
pursued in order to enhance the developmental impact of remittances, whether or not
remittances lead to growth in an absolute sense. The policies advocated include:
reaching out to diasporas working abroad, reducing the costs of sending remittances,
providing banking services for unbanked remittance senders and receivers, providing
investment and microenterprise opportunities for the remittance monies, encouraging
the use of hometown associations to channel money towards local development, and
marketing tourism and nostalgic trade to migrants. However, the range of policy
options will be greater with more information about the behavior of remittances in
various macroeconomic contexts.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
17/50
14
Chapter 3. Hypothesis and Statistical Model
This study extends the existing literature on remittances and growth, namely
the work of Chami et al. (2005), by considering the impact of remittances on economic
growth, while allowing for the impact of remittances to vary along several
macroeconomic lines. Like the work of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005), it includes
financial development, and its interaction with remittances, in the model, along with
several other macroeconomic country characteristics.
Hypothesis
The hypothesis of this study is that there are conditions under which
remittances will lead to economic growth. Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) have
demonstrated low financial development, measured by the depth of the banking
system, to be one of these cases. This research project investigates the impact of
remittances on growth at varying levels of gross capital formation and inflation as well.
Model
In order to probe the impact of remittances on growth, the following model is
estimated:
growthit = b0 +b1Remit +b2Zit +b3 (ZitRemit) +b4Xit + mt + hi + eit
where growthit is annual growth in per capita GDP in constant 2000 dollars, Remit is
remittances (workers remittances and compensation of employees received) as a
percentage of GDP, Zit is a vector of variables whose interactions with remittances are
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
18/50
15
being considered, and Xit is a vector of control variables whose interactions with
remittances are not being considered. Of interest are the coefficients b1 and b3, which
show respectively the impact of remittances on growth and how this effect varies with
other characteristics.
The Zit vector includes the following variables:
financial development (domestic credit provided by banking
sector/GDP)
investment/GDP (gross private capital formation/GDP)
inflation (annual percentage change in consumer prices)
Allowing all three of these variables to interact with remittances will paint a more
detailed picture of how remittances interact with other facets of the economy and show
the conditions under which they are the most economically productive. The Xit vector
consists only of population growth, expressed as annual percentage change.
Other variables tested for inclusion represented factors of production (arable
land and population density), capital sources (foreign direct investment), and degree of
openness (imports plus exports as a percentage of GDP). These variables were all
found to be insignificant and some, including arable land and population density,
varied by country but not over time, thus causing multi collinearity issues and proving
ineffective for fixed effects regressions. Additional variables of interest included fiscal
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
19/50
16
balance and measures of human capital, but these were not available annually for a
sufficient number of countries.
This study also estimates a model with a quadratic remittance term, as used in
one of the models of Chami et al. (2005). This model specification is:
growthit = b0 +b1Remit +b2Remit2 +b3Zit +b4 (ZitRemit) + b5Xit+ mt+ hi + eit
This model tests whether the impact of remittances on growth varies at different levels
of remittances.
Remittances are expressed as percentages of GDP throughout, as in Giuliano
and Ruiz Arranz (2005), rather than being differenced as in many of the models of
Chami et al. (2005), because the research question is concerned with the impact of the
flow of remittances on growth, rather than in the impact of marginal changes to this
flow on growth.
As stated in the hypothesis, the expectation is that remittances can positively
contribute to growth, so one would expect the coefficient on remittances to be positive.
The quadratic model specification is harder to predict. If remittances provide a
multiplier effect on growth, then the quadratic term should be significant. Glytsos
(2005) hints at this possibility in his research on how remittances impact growth in
Mediterranean countries through the pathways of consumption, investment, imports,
and income. If the impact of remittances on GDP growth is positive but decreasing
over time, then one would expect the quadratic term of remittances to have a negative
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
20/50
17
coefficient, while the linear term will have a positive coefficient. If the impact of
remittances is positive and cumulative over time, then one would expect the quadratic
term as well as the linear term to have positive coefficients. If the impact of
remittances is only felt in the present period, then the quadratic term should be
insignificant.
Based on literature in the field of economic growth, strong financial markets
and investment contribute to positive growth, so one would expect that the coefficient
of the measures of these two variables financial development and investment will
be positive. Given that inflation weakens the value of investment, and population
growth mitigates gains in GDP, the coefficients for these variables are expected to be
negative. Based on the results of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005), one would expect
the coefficient on remittances times credit to be negative, due to a crowding out effect.
With the exception of credit, the coefficients on the interaction terms of these variables
with remittances are difficult to predict, not being covered extensively in the literature.
The coefficient on the interaction of remittances and capital formation is complex
because growth depends on whether remittances are consumed or invested, whether
remittances crowd out other capital formation, and what type of returns to scale might
be present. Assuming, as this model does, that some portion of remittances would be
invested, the coefficient on remittances and inflation would likely be negative because
invested remittances are more likely to lead to growth at low levels of inflation.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
21/50
18
Chapter 4. Research Design
Data Sources
The dataset used in this analysis contains cross country, time series,
macroeconomic data from low and middle income countries, as classified by the World
Bank, for the period from 1990 to 2005. These data come from a variety of sources, but
are compiled in the World Banks World Development Indicators database. This
period of time is significantly shorter than those used by others previously. Chami et
al. (2005) look at the period from 1970 1998. Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005)
examine 1975 2002, using averages over five year periods. This study focuses on more
recent data because the reliability of the data on remittances has increased in recent
years as more money is sent through formal systems and as countries have become
more adept at tracking the flow of remittances.
Analytic Methodology
This research uses two main statistical methods. Five models of ordinary least
squares (OLS) regression are run. The first uses only remittances as an independent
variable to understand the degree of correlation present. Then linear and quadratic
models are run, both with and without regional dummy variables.
Next, fixed effects regressions are used to deal with the issue of autocorrelation
of the macroeconomic data. Three models are employed, the first using only
remittances as an independent variable, then the linear and quadratic models.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
22/50
19
Finally, the OLS and fixed effects regressions are repeated with the sample
broken apart by region to see if any region specific patterns emerge.
These models are compared to selected models employed by Chami et al.
(2005) and Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005). Chami et al. performed OLS regressions
of remittances (as a percentage of GDP) against growth. They included lagged GDP
per capita, investment to GDP ratio (logged), and net private capital formation (as a
percentage of GDP). In one specification, they included remittances squared as well. In
subsequent OLS and fixed effects regressions in their paper, they considered the
impact of the change in remittances on growth, which is beyond the scope of this
thesis, which considers the impact of the overall level of remittances on growth.
Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) regress a similar model with the dependent
variable being growth in real GDP per capita and the independent variables being
lagged real GDP per capita (logged), population growth (logged), fiscal balance,
investment to GDP ratio (logged), years of education (logged), imports plus exports (as
a percentage of GDP), inflation, and remittances (as a percentage of GDP). They use
OLS and fixed effects, along with generalized method of moments (GMM), to estimate
these models. They then estimate another model using OLS (and then GMM), adding
credit and an interaction term for remittances and credit (and then three other measures
of financial development, which this thesis does not address).
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
23/50
20
Chapter 5. Findings
Descriptive Statistics
The dataset used contains information for 152 low and middle income countries
(as classified by the World Bank) from 1990 to 2005, with 1,409 complete
observations. Tables 1 through 4 present an overview of the variables that are included
in the models. Tables 1 and 2 present the means of country quintiles ranked by real
GDP per capita in 1990 and 2000 tables 3 and 4 present the means of country quintiles
ranked by remittances as a percent of GDP in 1990 and 2000. More observations are
available for 2000 than for 1990 and for GDP per capita than for remittances, as seen
in the number of countries in each table. From Tables 3 and 4 one sees that the
difference between the first and fifth quintiles in remittances as a percentage of GDP is
much larger in 1990 than in 2000, so variation is decreasing over time. No
straightforward relationship between remittances and real GDP per capita emerges.
Table 1: Means of variables by quintiles of real GDP per capita (low to high)1990, 132 countries
Variable
1st
quintile
2nd
quintile
3rd
quintile
4th
quintile
5th
quintileReal GDP per capita
(US $, 2000) 216.51 486.99 1066.57 2038.00 4309.71Remittances
(as a percentage of GDP) 0.02 0.08 0.09 0.03 0.07Credit
(as a percentage of GDP) 25.02 60.40 38.62 46.48 46.60Gross capital formation
(as a percentage of GDP) 16.84 25.49 24.39 26.47 25.48Inflation (annual growth in
consumer prices) 23.54 430.32 15.28 412.34 326.00Population growth
(annual percentage) 2.48 2.39 2.05 1.73 1.00
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
24/50
21
Table 2: Means of variables by quintiles of real GDP per capita (low to high)2000, 141 countries
Variable1st
quintile2nd
quintile3rd
quintile4th
quintile5th
quintile
Real GDP per capita(US $, 2000) 216.27 491.66 1091.75 2245.10 5227.11
Remittances(as a percentage of GDP) 0.02 0.06 0.07 0.04 0.01
Credit(as a percentage of GDP) 32.67 20.46 45.37 34.76 66.39
Gross capital formation(as a percentage of GDP) 17.88 24.65 21.52 21.22 24.93
Inflation (annual growth inconsumer prices) 30.98 8.44 26.82 11.36 4.51
Population growth(annual percentage) 2.72 1.57 0.60 1.36 1.03
Table 3: Means of variables by quintiles of remittances as a percentage of GDP(low to high), 1990, 82 countries
Variable
1stquintile
2ndquintile
3rdquintile
4thquintile
5thquintile
Real GDP per capita(US $, 2000) 1682.98 1830.81 1768.69 1072.10 1771.25
Remittances
(as a percentage of GDP) 0.00 0.01 0.02 0.04 0.22Credit(as a percentage of GDP) 46.09 44.48 32.40 31.03 44.59
Gross capital formation(as a percentage of GDP) 19.22 22.84 20.80 22.90 33.50
Inflation (annual growth inconsumer prices) 197.89 516.26 18.16 14.61 14.60
Population growth(annual percentage) 2.11 2.55 2.12 2.35 1.62
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
25/50
22
Table 4: Means of variables by quintiles of remittances as a percentage of GDP(low to high), 2000, 120 countries
Variable
1st
quintile
2nd
quintile
3rd
quintile
4th
quintile
5th
quintileReal GDP per capita
(US $, 2000) 3021.13 2086.25 1946.64 1264.13 1335.45Remittances
(as a percentage of GDP) 0.00 0.01 0.01 0.04 0.14Credit
(as a percentage of GDP) 36.00 39.33 44.03 37.54 50.98Gross capital formation
(as a percentage of GDP) 21.32 22.51 22.72 21.80 23.59Inflation (annual growth in
consumer prices) 10.21 6.69 12.53 3.83 11.07Population growth
(annual percentage) 1.61 1.46 1.71 1.67 0.40
Charts 1 and 2 present scatter plots of remittances as a percentage of GDP
versus real GDP per capita on log scales for the years 1990 and 2000. This form of
presentation demonstrates where countries and regions stand relative to one another.
Some countries change position significantly during this ten year period. China
experiences a growth in both GDP per capita and remittances (as a percentage of
GDP), while Egypt and Lebanon have an increase in GDP per capita but a decrease in
remittances (as a percentage of GDP). Other countries, such as Mexico and El
Salvador, remain in essentially the same position. However, from this representation
no straightforward relationship between the two main variables of interest is observed.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
26/50
23
Chart 1: Remittances/GDP vs. real GDP per capita, 1990
Oman
Seychelles
St. Kitts and Nevis
Mexico
Trinidad and Tobago
St. Lucia
South Africa
Dominica
Costa Rica
Brazil
Lebanon
Grenada
Jamaica
Panama
Malaysia
St. Vincent and the Grenadines
Turkey
Belize
Botswana
Suriname
Colombia
Algeria
Peru
El Salvador
Namibia
Jordan
Dominican Republic
Paraguay
Tunisia
Thailand
Guatemala
Swaziland
Ecuador
Tonga
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Samoa
Morocco
Vanuatu
Philippines
Honduras
Syrian Arab Republic
Bolivia
Cape Verde
Cameroon
Cote d'Ivoire
Zimbabwe
Haiti
Indonesia
Sri Lanka
Papua New Guinea
Pakistan
Yemen, Rep.
Kenya
Kiribati
Comoros
Senegal
China
Lesotho
Nigeria
Mauritania
Gambia, The
India
Bangladesh
Benin
Sudan
Madagascar
Togo
Rwanda
Lao PDR
Ghana
Burkina Faso
Guinea Bissau
Mali
Niger
Mozambique
Ethiopia
0.0001
0.001
0.01
0.1
1
$100 $1,000 $10,000
Real GDP per capita (Log scale)
Remittances/GDP(Logscale)
Chart 2: Remittances/GDP vs. real GDP per capita, 2000
Ethiopia
Sierra Leone
Malawi
Niger
Guinea Bissau
Eritrea
Mali
Mozambique
Nepal
Rwanda
Burkina Faso
Madagascar
Uganda
Togo
Ghana
Tanzania
Cambodia
Moldova
Benin
Gambia, The
Lao PDR
Bangladesh
Nigeria
Guinea
Sudan Comoros
Mongolia
Mauritania
KenyaSenegal
India
Haiti
Lesotho
Yemen, Rep.
Pakistan
Kiribati
Armenia
Cote d'Ivoire
Ukraine
Papua New Guinea
Georgia
Azerbaijan
Cameroon
Solomon Islands
Nicaragua
Indonesia
Sri LankaHonduras
Congo, Rep.
China
Guyana
Philippines
Bolivia
Serbia and Montenegro
Syrian Arab Republic
Bosnia and Herzegovina
Cape Verde
Morocco
Albania
Kazakhstan
Belarus
Vanuatu
Ecuador
Samoa
Swaziland
Paraguay
Egypt, Arab Rep.
Bulgaria
West Bank and Gaza
Iran, Islamic Rep.
Romania
Guatemala
Algeria
Russian Federation
Jordan
Macedonia, FYR
Namibia
Colombia
Thailand
Tunisia
FijiPeru
El Salvador
Maldives
Dominican Republic
St. Vincent and the Grenadines
Turkey
Botswana
South Africa
Jamaica
Lithuania
Latvia
Belize
Brazil
Slovak Republic
Mauritius
Dominica
Gabon
Malaysia
Panama
Estonia
Grenada
Costa Rica
Croatia
St. Lucia
Poland
Hungary
Venezuela, RB
Lebanon
Chile
Czech Republic
Mexico
Trinidad and Tobago
Libya
St. Kitts and Nevis
Argentina
Oman
0.0001
0.001
0.01
0.1
1
$100 $1,000 $10,000
Real GDP per capita (Log scale)
Remittances/GDP(Logscale)
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
27/50
24
Regression Results
Ordinary Least Squares
Table 5 presents the results of OLS regression of growth in real GDP per capita
against various independent variables using five models that replicate, to some degree,
those used by Chami et al. (2005) and Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005). The inclusion
of the quadratic term for remittances in Models III and V mirrors a similar term in one
of the models of Chami et al. (2005). The first model uses only remittances (as a
percentage of GDP) as an independent variable and finds them positively and
significantly correlated with growth. Model II includes other independent variables
domestic credit provided by the banking sector and gross capital formation (both
expressed as percentages of GDP) as well as inflation and population growth. In this
model, remittances are no longer significant whereas the other variables are. Model III
uses all of the variables in Model II and adds a quadratic term for remittances and
interaction terms for remittances with credit, gross capital formation, and inflation. In
this specification, both remittances and remittances squared are significant. Models IV
and V repeat Models II and III respectively with regional dummies, using the regional
categories employed by the World Bank: East Asia and Pacific, Europe and Central
Asia, Latin America, Middle East and North Africa, South Asia, and Sub Saharan
Africa.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
28/50
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
29/50
26
Comparing Models II and III (or IV and V), one sees that the addition of
remittances squared and the various interaction terms with remittances does not have a
great impact on the sign, magnitude, or significance of most of the coefficients. The
big exception to this is the coefficient on remittances, which changes both in
significance and magnitude.
Comparing Models II and III to Models IV and V with regional dummy
variables, one also sees that the regional dummies reduce the magnitude of the
coefficients, but only slightly. The regional dummy coefficients themselves are
interesting to examine. With Latin America as the base category, all of the other
regions experience significantly higher growth, ranging between 1 and 2 percentage
points, with the exception of Sub Saharan Africa. The fact that Latin America joins
Africa in lower than average growth is probably due to the years selected for the
sample. The debt crisis and slow growth were characteristic of Latin America in 1990s.
Models III and V find both remittances and the square of remittances to be
significant and to positively contribute to growth. This implies that as remittances
increase, they have an increasingly large positive impact on growth, i.e., that there is
some sort of multiplier effect at work. This result reinforces the work of Glytsos (2005)
who hypothesizes and calculates a Keynesian multiplier for the effect of remittances on
growth, through various pathways consumption, investment, imports, and income.
The coefficient of credit (that is, domestic credit supplied by the banking
sector) is negative and significant, meaning that growth is higher in countries that have
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
30/50
27
less access to credit. This appears to be counterintuitive and is inconsistent with the
results of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) who find that domestic credit available is a
good proxy for financial development and contributes to growth. If the coefficient for
credit had switched signs from Model II to Model III, then it could possibly reflect a
crowding out effect of remittances on credit. However, because the coefficient of credit
remains near constant in both magnitude and significance, this does not appear to be
the case. The negative correlation between credit and growth is explored in greater
detail in the Appendix, where it is broken apart by year and region. It appears to be
another artifact of the 1990s debt crisis.
Gross capital formation has the expected positive sign, underlining that
countries with more capital will experience greater growth. Inflation and population
growth are both also found to contribute negatively to growth, which is also as
expected.
Looking at the interaction terms of remittances and the other variables in
Models III and V suggests interesting features of how remittances work. The
coefficient on credit times remittances is negative and significant. This would suggest
that remittances have a more positive impact on growth in countries with less access to
credit. Remittances may serve as a substitute for credit when it is not available. This is
consistent with the findings of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) although, as
mentioned above, the coefficient on credit alone is not. The coefficient on gross capital
formation times remittances is also negative and significant, suggesting that
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
31/50
28
remittances have a more positive impact on growth in countries with lower levels of
capital. This result shows that remittances play a different role in countries with greater
capital. In countries with higher capital levels, remittances are not used for investment
in the way that they appear to be in countries with lower capital levels. Finally, the
interaction term of inflation and remittances is also negative and significant, suggesting
that remittances have a larger impact on growth in countries with low inflation. This
could be due to the fact that countries with lower inflation rates enjoy a better
investment climate and remittances are more likely to be invested in that setting. The
dollarization or dual currency economy in high inflation economies may also impact
the effect of remittances on growth, but little research has been done in this area.
These results differ quite significantly from other studies of remittances and
development, namely Chami et al. (2005) and Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005). In the
OLS regressions of Chami et al. (2005), remittances were found to be insignificant,
both with and without regional dummies. Including the quadratic term of remittances
as well, they found the squared term to be significant at the 10% level with a negative
coefficient. The linear term, while insignificant, had a positive coefficient. In
subsequent OLS regressions, Chami et al. include a differenced term for remittances
(dlog) and find it to be significant and negative.
In the OLS model of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005), they find remittances to
be insignificant in contributing to growth. In their next set of model, which add various
measures of financial development (credit being one) and an interaction term for
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
32/50
29
remittances and financial development, they find remittances to be significant and to
positively contribute to growth. They also find that the coefficient on credit (along with
the other three measures of financial development) is significant and positive, which is
a departure from the negative coefficient on credit here. (For further explanation on
this issue, see the Appendix.) Finally, they find that the interaction term of remittances
and credit is significant and negative, indicating that remittances have a greater
contribution to growth in countries with low levels of financial development. Their
results are consistent with the findings of this paper.
The models presented here have relatively low R2values, reaching only about
0.20. These low levels ofR2 are consistent with other literature in the field, for Chami
et al. (2005), R2reached 0.27 and for Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005), it reached
0.36. Higher values would be obtained with the inclusion of a lagged GDP variable,
but adding lagged GDP creates problems with autocorrelation.
The problem of autocorrelation bias arises here with macroeconomic data used
in cross country analysis. Because of the high degree of serial correlation of
macroeconomic data, the error terms for each country are likely correlated over time.
To deal with this problem, fixed effects regressions are run below. Other possible
sources of bias are mentioned below after the fixed effects results are presented.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
33/50
30
Fixed effects estimation
Table 6 presents the results of fixed effects estimation of the same dataset. The
three models considered correspond to the first three models in Table 5 and the results
are consistent in sign and significance, though generally the coefficients are smaller.
Table 6: Remittances and growth: Fixed effects cross sectional estimation (1990 2005, 152 countries)
Dependent variable:
Annual growth in realGDP per capita
I II IIIwith interaction
terms
Constant0.714
(1.26)0.286
(0.33)1.127
( 1.22)
Remittances(as a percentage of GDP)
19.550***(5.43)
5.583(1.33)
21.867**(2.42)
Remittances2 49.027***
(3.30)
Credit(as a percentage of GDP)
0.052***( 6.29)
0.044***( 5.13)
Credit * remittances 0.173*( 1.91)
Gross capital formation(as a percentage of GDP)
0.202***(7.72)
0.250***(8.80)
Gross capital formation *remittances
0.853***( 4.04)
Inflation (annual growthin consumer prices)
0.0015***( 3.45)
0.00088*( 1.65)
Inflation * remittances 0.191**( 2.27)
Population growth(annual percentage)
0.462***( 3.42)
0.393***( 2.92)
number of observations 1,621 1,409 1,409
R2 0.2466 0.3441 0.3604
Adjusted R2 0.1720 0.2729 0.2886
Durbin Watson statistic 1.933 1.899 2.099
Note: Value oftstatistics in parentheses * significant at 10 percent ** significant at 5 percent*** significant at 1 percent.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
34/50
31
The one exception to the coefficients being smaller is in Model I, which regresses only
remittances against growth. The coefficient is significant, positive, and about four
times larger in the fixed effects regression, compared to the OLS regression.
As in the OLS regression, remittances are not found to be significant in the
linear model. The signs, significance, and magnitude of the coefficients suggest the
same interpretations presented with the OLS regressions above. The fixed effects
regression, by considering each country separately, does address possible
autocorrelation problems. The Durbin Watson statistics presented in Table 6 indicate
that there is no autocorrelation present in these regressions.
Comparing these models to the fixed effects models of Chami et al. (2005) and
Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005), several notable differences again arise. Chami et al.
include only the differenced remittances term in their fixed effects regressions and find
it to be negative and significant, though smaller in magnitude than in the OLS
regressions. As in their OLS regression, Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz find the remittance
term in their fixed effects regression to be positive but insignificant. They do not
perform the subsequent regression including the interaction of remittances and credit
with the fixed effect model.
As in the OLS models above, the fixed effects regressions also exhibit low R2
values. For these fixed effects regressions, they range up to 0.36. For comparison, the
highest R2values obtained in the fixed effects regressions by Chami et al. (2005) and
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
35/50
32
Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005) were 0.39 and 0.68 respectively. Higher R2could be
obtained with the inclusion of other variables discussed below.
Several variables were tested in these regressions, both OLS and fixed effects,
but found to be insignificant and excluded. These include the percentage of arable land
and population density, as indicators of factors of production imports plus exports
(both as a percentages of GDP), as used in the models of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz
(2005) and foreign direct investment (as a percentage of GDP), another international
capital flow and possible driver of growth. Other variables of interest, but with limited
availability for a sufficiently large portion of the sample on an annual basis, included
fiscal balance (i.e., government surplus) and human capital. Studies in the literature
(Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz, 2005 Adams and Page, 2005) use these variables as
indictors of the basic macroeconomic relationship and the effect of education on
investment. The exclusion of these variables raises the possibility of omitted variable
bias. In the case of human capital, this likely leads to a positive bias in the coefficient
on remittances because high levels of human capital are associated both with higher
levels of growth and with higher levels of migration and remittance sending. The bias
caused by the omission of fiscal balance is likely to be downward, understating the
impact of remittances on growth. There is generally a positive correlation between
fiscal balance and growth, but assuming, as Chami et al. (2005) do, that remittances are
countercyclical, they will be lower when fiscal balance is higher.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
36/50
33
Another potential source of bias in the results is the endogeneity of remittances.
Remittances are very stable over time, and, as mentioned above, often assumed to be
counter cyclical. As seen in Table 9 in the Appendix, there is a negative correlation
between remittances and real GDP per capita. Because of this endogeneity, the positive
impact of remittances estimated here is likely understated.
Regional breakdown (using OLS and fixed effects)
Although the results in Tables 5 and 6 present a positive and convincing view
of remittances, the case is weaker when the regions are considered separately. Tables 7
and 8 present the results of OLS and fixed effect regressions respectively where each
region is considered in its own model. The model estimated corresponds to Model III
in Tables 5 and 6, containing remittances squared and all interaction terms. In the OLS
estimations in Table 7, remittances and remittances squared, along with most of the
interaction terms, lose all of their significance. The variation in growth is explained
mostly by gross capital formation, along with credit, inflation, and population growth
to a lesser degree.
Although both the linear and quadratic terms of remittances are largely
insignificant in these models, it is interesting to note the variations in sign across the
regions. In East Asia and the Pacific and the Middle East and North Africa, both terms
have positive signs, suggesting that the positive impact of remittances on growth
increases as remittances rise. In Europe and Central Asia, Latin America, and South
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
37/50
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
38/50
35
A note of caution is necessary for these regressions. Breaking the data apart by
region in this way leads to very small sample sizes, ranging from 79 observations in
South Asia to 417 in Sub Saharan Africa. Although they form an interesting point of
comparison, they do not offer as much statistical significance as the worldwide cross
country regressions presented above.
In the fixed effects estimations in Table 8, remittances are significant in Europe
and Central Asia, Latin America, and the Middle East and North Africa. All of these
regions find a positive impact of remittances on growth. Remittances squared are
significant in East Asia and the Pacific and Europe and Central Asia, although they are
negative in the former and positive in the latter.
The impact of remittances on growth by region is markedly different for these
fixed effects regressions than for the OLS regressions above. Again, putting aside the
issue of statistical significance, the region of Europe and Central Asia is the only one
that has both coefficients positive, leading to the multiplier effect of remittances on
growth seen in the world wide analysis. Latin America and the Middle East and North
Africa have positive coefficients on the linear term, but negative coefficients on the
quadratic term, which shows that remittances initially contribute to growth, but at
higher levels inhibit growth. East Asia and the Pacific and South Asia, have negative
coefficients on both terms, meaning that remittances inhibit growth in all cases.
Finally, Sub Saharan Africa has a negative coefficient on the linear term and a positive
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
39/50
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
40/50
37
They add to growth in an absolute sense with ever increasing returns. Their impact is
strongest in countries with low levels of domestic credit available, low levels of capital
formation, and low levels of inflation.
This study draws from and builds on previous studies, but provides a more
robust analysis for several reasons. By employing recent data, going back only as far as
1990, the remittance figures are more accurate. As remittance sending fees have been
falling over time, more money is being sent through official channels and global
financial tracking programs are getting better at determining the capital flows around
the world. Other major advantages of the models presented here are the inclusion of
numerous interaction terms, which allow a greater understanding of how remittances
and growth interact in differing economic situations, and the inclusion of the quadratic
term for remittances, which allows the impact of remittances to vary with their relative
size in the economy.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
41/50
38
Chapter 6. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations
This study has contributed to the literature on remittances and development
with a model that accounts for the increasing reliability of remittance data in recent
years and that allows for variation in the impact of remittances by several
macroeconomic factors. The results suggest that remittances have a positive impact on
growth and that this impact becomes even stronger at higher levels of remittances
relative to GDP. Additionally, remittances are found to have a more positive impact in
countries with certain characteristics: low domestic credit available, low capital
formation, and low inflation. Further study both on the micro and macro levels should
investigate the pathways through which remittances promote economic growth, e.g., by
funding imports that can promote efficiency and make investment more profitable
(Glytsos, 2005).
The conclusions of this research project can help to inform several levels of
policy that could encourage economic growth in developing countries. Since higher
levels of remittances are found to lead to accelerated economic growth, the study
provides justification for the policy recommendations mentioned in the literature
(Kapur, 2004 Sriskandarajah, 2005 Terry & Wilson, 2005 Brown, 2006 Orozco &
Fedewa, 2006), which include policies to encourage migration and remittances
(lowering the costs of sending remittances, making international labor markets more
flexible, promoting circular migration, and encouraging collective remittances) and
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
42/50
39
policies to help those remittances become more economically productive (providing
banking services for unbanked remittance senders and receivers and providing
investment and microenterprise opportunities for the remittance monies).
But the policy implications of this study go even further, since information is
obtained on the behavior of remittances in various macroeconomic contexts.
Remittances appear to foster the most growth in countries that have lower levels of
credit available, lower levels of capital formation, and lower levels of inflation. This
information could be used by international organizations or donor agencies to
concentrate their remittance and development projects on countries fitting this profile,
in order to produce the largest positive effect on growth, or to couple their work on
remittances with efforts to control inflation. On a country level, these results can be
used to help form a macroeconomic context that will be the most receptive to
remittances fostering economic growth. Although countries would understandably be
hesitant to limiting credit or restrict capital formation, the central banks role in
controlling inflation becomes obviously important, knowing that doing so can help
remittances to become more economically productive in that environment. In time the
economic growth stimulated by these remittances may help create a situation where
families no longer need to be divided by continents or national borders in order to find
productive work and support one another. This growth stimulating aspect of
remittances and migration should not be ignored in the current political debates about
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
43/50
40
immigration in developed countries. The potential for economic growth and poverty
reduction in developing countries must be considered among the complex set of issues
involved in the formulation of immigration policy.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
44/50
41
Appendix: Correlations between variables
This appendix examines correlations between the dependent and independent
variables of interest, concentrating on remittances (the main variable of interest) and
credit. The focus on credit arises because there is a negative coefficient on credit in
both the OLS and fixed effects models, contrary to the theory that credit constraints
can restrict growth and contrary to the findings of Giuliano and Ruiz Arranz (2005).
Table 9: Correlations between remittances, credit, and other variables
remittances
(as a percentage of GDP)
credit
(as a percentage of GDP)
Variable correlationcoefficient
probability of
significance
correlation
coefficient
probability of
significance
Annual growth in realGDP per capita
0.06661 0.0073 0.04761 0.0331
Credit(as a percentage of GDP)
0.02671 0.2748 1.0000
Remittances(as a percentage of GDP)
1.0000 0.02671 0.2748
Gross capital formation(as a percentage of GDP)
0.26013
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
45/50
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
46/50
43
References
Acosta, Pablo, Cesar Calderon, Pablo Fajnzylber, and Humberto Lopez (2006).
Remittances and Development in Latin America. The World Economy, 29(7):
957 987.
Adams, Richard H., Jr. (2005). Remittances, Household Expenditure and Investment in
Guatemala. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, No. 3532.
Adams, R., and J. Page (2005). Do International Migration and Remittances Reduce
Poverty in Developing Countries? World Development, 33(10): 1645 69.
Aggarwal, Reena, Asli Demirguc Kunt, and Maria Soledad Martinez Peria (2006). Do
workers' remittances promote financial development? World Bank Policy
Research Working Paper, No. 3957.
Basok, Tanya (2003). Mexican Seasonal Migration to Canada and Development: A
Community based Comparison. International Migration, 41(2): 3 26.
Bracking, Sarah (2003). Sending Money Home: Are Remittances Always Beneficial
To Those Who Stay Behind? Journal of International Development, 15(5):
633644.
Brown, Stuart S. (2006). Can Remittances Spur Development? A Critical Survey.
International Studies Review 8(1): 55 76.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
47/50
44
Buch, Claudia M., and Anja Kuckulenz (2004). Worker Remittances and Capital Flows
to Developing Countries. Centre for European Economic Research Discussion
Paper No. 04 31.
Bugamelli, Matteo, and Francesco Patern (2005). Do workers remittances reduce the
probability of current account reversals? World Bank Policy Research Working
Paper, No. 3766.
Chami, Ralph, Connel Fullenkamp, Samir Jahjah (2005). Are Immigrant Remittance
Flows a Source of Capital for Development? IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 52.
DeSipio, Louis (2000). Sending Money Home...for Now: Remittances and Immigrant
Adaptation in the United States. Available online at
http://www.thedialogue.org/publications/Desipio.pdf.
Ellerman, David (2003). Policy Research on Migration and Development. World Bank
Policy Research Working Paper, No. 3117.
El Sakka, M. I. T., and Robert McNabb (1999). The Macroeconomic Determinants of
Emigrant Remittances. World Development, 27(8): 1493 1502.
Gammeltoft, Peter (2002). Remittances and Other Financial Flows to Developing
Countries. International Migration, 40(5): 181 209.
Giuliano, Paola, and Marta Ruiz Arranz (2005). Remittances, Financial Development
and Growth. International Monetary Fund Working Paper 05/234.
Glytsos, N.P. (2005). The contribution of remittances to growth. Journal of Economic
Studies, 32(6): 468 496.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
48/50
45
Gupta ,Sanjeev, Catherine Pattillo, and Smita Wagh (2007). Impact of Remittances on
Poverty and Financial Development in Sub Saharan Africa. IMF Working
Paper 07/38.
International Monetary Fund (1993). Balance of Payments Manual, Fifth Edition.
Washington, D.C.
International Monetary Fund (2005). Two Current Issues Facing Developing
Countries. In World Economic Outlook 2005: Globalization and External
Imbalances, pp. 69 107. Washington, D.C.
Kanaiaupuni, Shawn Malia, and Katharine M. Donato (1999). Migradollars and
Mortality: The Effects of Migration on Infant Survival in Mexico. Domgraphy,
36(3): 339 353.
Kapur, Devesh (2004). Remittances: The New Development Mantra? United Nations
G 24 Discussion Paper Series, No. 29.
Lowell, Lindsay, and Rodolfo O. de la Garza (2004). The Developmental Role of
Remittances in US Latino Communities and in Latin American Countries.
Institute for the Study of International Migration, University of Texas Austin.
Lueth, Erik, and Marta Ruiz Arranz (2006). A Gravity Model of Workers
Remittances. IMF Working Paper 06/290.
Mundaca, Gabriela (2005). Can Remittances Enhance Economic Growth? The Role of
Financial Market Development. Downloaded from SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=799484.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
49/50
46
Orozco, Manuel (2004). Mexican Hometown Associations and Development Finance
Opportunities. Journal of International Affairs, 57(2): 31 52.
Orozco, Manuel, and Rachel Fedewa (2006). Leveraging Efforts on Remittances and
Financial Intermediation. INTAL ITD Working Paper 24. Downloaded from
www.thedialogue.org/publications/2007/winter/orozco_intermediation.pdf.
Page, John, and Sonia Plaza (2005). Migration Remittances and Development: A
Review of Global Evidence. Paper presented at the Plenary Session of the
African Economic Research Consortium, May 29, 2005.
Rapoport, Hillel, and Frdric Docquier (2005). The Economics of Migrants
Remittances. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 1531. Downloaded from
http://ssrn.com/abstract=690144.
Ratha, Dilip (2003). Workers Remittances: An Important and Stable Source of
External Development Finance. In Global Development Finance: Striving for
Stability in Development Finance, pp. 20 51. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Reinke, Jens, and Neil Patterson (2005). Remittances in the Balance of Payments
Framework. Presented at International Technical Meeting on Measuring
Remittances, World Bank, Washington, D.C., January 24 25, 2005. Available
online at http://www.imf.org/external/np/sta/bop/pdf/rem.pdf.
Roberts, Kenneth D., and Michael Morris (2004). Fortune, Risk and Remittances: an
Application of Option Theory to Participation in Village based Migration
Networks. International Migration Review, 37(4): 1252 1281.
-
8/3/2019 Akram Thesis
50/50
Sana, Mariano (2005). Buying membership in the transnational community: migrant
remittances, social status, and assimilation. Population Research and Policy
Review. 24(3): 231 261.
Sana, Mariano, and Douglas S. Massey (2005). Household Composition, Family
Migration and Community Context. Migrant Remittances in Four Countries.
Social Science Quarterly 86(2): 509 528.
Sriskandarajah, Dhananjayan (2005). Towards fairer flows: policies to optimise the
impact of migration on economic development. A paper prepared for the Policy
Analysis and Research Programme of the Global Commission on International
Migration.
Terry, Donald F., and Steven R. Wilson, eds. (2005). Beyond Small Change: Making
Migrant Remittances Count. Washington, D. C.: Inter American Development
Bank. http://0 site.ebrary.com.library.lausys.georgetown.edu/lib/georgetown/
Doc?id=10089796
World Bank (2006a). Global Economic Prospects 2006: Economic Implications of
Remittances and Migration. Washington, D.C.
World Bank (2006b). World Development Indicators. Accessed online at http://0
devdata.worldbank.org.library.lausys.georgetown.edu/dataonline/.
Ziesemer, Thomas (2006). Worker Remittances and Growth: The Physical and Human
Capital Channels. UNU MERIT Working paper #2006 020.